Fortune News | Jan 25,2020
Dec 30 , 2023
By Ian Ayres , Aaron Edlin and Berkeley. Robert J. Shiller
European Union (EU) lawmakers recently reached a provisional agreement on a landmark regulation to mitigate the risks that artificial intelligence (AI) poses to humanity. Other countries seem ready to follow the EU's lead.
But this regulation does not address one of the greatest disasters AI may bring – the prospect of mass unemployment and sharply increased income inequality. Regulation cannot eliminate these risks without precluding the world from enjoying AI's potential benefits: dramatic increases in productivity and enormous wealth creation. That is why policymakers must also enact policies to compensate citizens if these disasters occur.
Let us be clear. We are not opposed to regulating AI. But just as we take a two-pronged approach to protect flood-vulnerable homes – building sea walls and providing flood insurance – so, too, must governments offer inequality insurance to ensure that AI does not widen the wealth gap. While future administrations could conceivably change the terms of such a program, cutting back on widely experienced benefits would be politically difficult.
The writing is already on the wall. This year, Hollywood actors joined screenwriters in the first industry-wide strike in more than six decades, with safeguards against generative AI being one of their main demands. But AI will revolutionise the future of work for all types of professionals, from doctors and lawyers to taxi drivers and checkout clerks. The subsequent increases in total output will not be shared equally. Those who make and own the inventions could amass immense wealth, much of which will come from economising on labour costs.
It is tempting to believe that AI will turn huge swaths of the workforce into hamburger flippers, but even that job is being automated. Perhaps there will be other low-value services for people to provide. If not, the ranks of the chronically unemployed will swell. Either way, income disparities will almost surely deepen.
Policymakers can limit, or even prevent, the resulting increases in inequality by reforming the tax system.
For example, if inequality exceeds certain limits, federal income-tax rates on high earners could increase automatically. To stop inequality from rising further, taxes on the top one percent could be set each year to ensure that their share of total national after-tax income never rises above current levels.
To be sure, if AI causes truly catastrophic increases in inequality – say, if the top one percent were to receive all pretax income – there might be limits to what tax reforms could accomplish.
Consider a country where the top one percent earns 20pc of pretax income – roughly the current world average. If, owing to AI, this group eventually received all pretax income, it would need to be taxed at a rate of 80pc, with the revenue redistributed as tax credits to the 99pc, to achieve today's pretax income distribution; funding the government and achieving today's post-tax income distribution would require an even higher rate.
Given that such high rates could discourage work, we would likely have to settle for partial inequality insurance, analogous to having a deductible on a conventional insurance policy to reduce moral hazard.
Such a lopsided income distribution is unlikely, and in less extreme cases, full or nearly full inequality insurance would be possible and warranted. But while this thought experiment highlights a weakness of our plan – it cannot provide full insurance in the most catastrophic cases – it also points to the importance of building some form of automatic insurance into the tax system. After all, most people would agree that if economic inequality does spike, the one percent should be taxed at a substantially higher rate than they are today.
To deal with the massive unemployment that AI may bring, many – from Juliet Rhys-Williams in 1943 to US presidential candidate Andrew Yang in 2018 – have proposed a guaranteed minimum basic income for everyone, regardless of what they do. Other economists, such as the Nobel laureate Edmund Phelps, have instead suggested subsidising wages by expanding the negative income tax for low-income families or adjusting corporate tax deductions.
Either way, these plans require funding, and building inequality insurance into the tax system could be a long-term adjustment.
Even though our proposal does not cap the amount of money people can earn or save, we are under no illusions that establishing inequality insurance will be politically easy. But too much is at stake not to try. As US Supreme Court Justice Louis Brandeis put it, we can have democracy or great wealth concentrated in the hands of the few, but not both.
Two aspects of our proposal make it more politically feasible than a traditional tax.
The cap on inequality can be set above current levels – meaning that it would not be triggered immediately. Psychologists have shown that people are more idealistic when deciding about the distant future rather than the present. Because voters do not know their future income bracket, they will likely decide in favour of inequality insurance based on abstract moral principles.
If the insurance is triggered, the beneficiary class would be much greater in number than the top earners paying the higher marginal rate. The transfer of wealth from the one percent should go to the bottom half of earners, although it could conceivably be shared with higher earners to garner their support. Once the insurance kicks in, the legislation could eventually lower taxes for most workers.
Explicitly defining tax rates to provide insurance against extreme inequality was a good idea when one of us first proposed it two decades ago. But it is a much better idea today. To reap AI's benefits, we must prepare for a potentially catastrophic increase in wealth and income disparities.
PUBLISHED ON
Dec 30,2023 [ VOL
24 , NO
1235]
Fortune News | Jan 25,2020
Radar | Apr 15,2023
Life Matters | Mar 09,2019
Fortune News | Dec 07,2019
Radar | Dec 02,2023
Commentaries | Dec 19,2021
Sunday with Eden | Apr 24,2021
Sponsored Contents | Dec 20,2024
Viewpoints | Mar 30,2024
My Opinion | 118681 Views | Aug 14,2021
My Opinion | 114731 Views | Aug 21,2021
My Opinion | 113484 Views | Sep 10,2021
My Opinion | 111415 Views | Aug 07,2021
Life Matters | Dec 21,2024
Agenda | Dec 22,2024
Dec 22 , 2024 . By TIZITA SHEWAFERAW
Charged with transforming colossal state-owned enterprises into modern and competitiv...
Aug 18 , 2024 . By AKSAH ITALO
Although predictable Yonas Zerihun's job in the ride-hailing service is not immune to...
Jul 28 , 2024 . By TIZITA SHEWAFERAW
Unhabitual, perhaps too many, Samuel Gebreyohannes, 38, used to occasionally enjoy a couple of beers at breakfast. However, he recently swit...
Jul 13 , 2024 . By AKSAH ITALO
Investors who rely on tractors, trucks, and field vehicles for commuting, transporting commodities, and f...
Dec 21 , 2024
The main avenues and thoroughfares of Addis Abeba have undergone an impressive faceli...
Dec 14 , 2024
Ethiopia's monetary policy has shifted conspicuously in recent years. Gone is the era...
Dec 7 , 2024
For decades the Ethiopian Petroleum Supply Enterprise (EPSE), a state-owned giant ent...
Nov 30 , 2024
In the corridors of government offices worldwide, the question of how much to pay mem...
Dec 22 , 2024 . By AKSAH ITALO
The Harer city administration has shut down 43 bank branches, including those of Comm...
Dec 22 , 2024 . By BEZAWIT HULUAGER
The Addis Abeba Revenue Bureau's new salary standards for tax purposes have caused ba...
Dec 22 , 2024 . By BEZAWIT HULUAGER
An audit report presented to Parliament last week revealed financial irregularities a...
Dec 22 , 2024 . By AKSAH ITALO
The legal battle between BGI Ethiopia, a leading brewery, and Zewdnesh G. Asrat has c...