The Don'ts of Floating the Birr


Feb 12 , 2022
By Christian Tesfaye


One of the stubborn policies of successive governments in Ethiopia has been an inflexible exchange rate regime. Administrations have protected this area from liberalisation, arguing that this would result in a financial crisis of the sort that began in Asia in 1997. It is not a secret that countries loose with their exchange rates suffered the most back then.

But it would be unfair to characterise flexible exchange rate controls solely based on the infamous Asian crisis, as many left-leaning pundits tend to do. If anything, its failure then shows that no theory or model holds up under every single scenario. The right set of conditions need to align for such a critical part of monetary policy to do good. We need to ask if these conditions are aligning for Ethiopia as well instead of whether flexible exchange rates are helpful.



Mulling this issue, we need to look at one crucial factor that often does not get sufficient consideration concerning exchange rates, inflation (and, subsequently, economic output). Sure, foreign currency reserves are most directly concerned. But a government does not keep a healthy reserve to maintain a score of some sort. It is to ensure that the domestic currency maintains its value and economic output is on the up and up.

Let us consider lifting exchange rate controls under Ethiopia's current inflationary pressure environment.

What would happen?

An immediate effect would be that the formal and black market rates would equalise. People and businesses with foreign currency would no longer need to take their dollars and euros underground to get better returns in Birr. One point for the proponents of a flexible exchange rate regime.

But this will happen as well. With inflation hovering around 35pc, not many would want to hold Birr except for day-to-day spending. They will attempt to hold a large chunk of their savings in dollars. The demand for foreign currencies will explode while that of the Birr would fall far more than it is already doing under a pegged exchange rate regime.

At this point, the National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE) will be alarmed and place back exchange rate controls. But let us say that policymakers are determined to see through a flexible exchange rate policy and attempt to save the Birr from depreciation in value through other tools as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) would recommend.

The central bank has lost exchange rates as a monetary policy instrument. Remaining in its toolkit are interest rates and the power of money creation. The latter is only useful to do the opposite, to devalue the Birr more. The economy needs less Birr in circulation so that demand for the currency will pick up once again.

Higher borrowing costs will suck Birr out of the economy, so the central bank will want to raise interest rates. More people will be incentivised to save, decreasing the velocity of money circulation. This also makes borrowing expensive, discouraging credit.

Inflation could be contained but at what cost?

Higher borrowing costs will mean that companies will find taking out loans expensive. The same goes for the federal government, which has increasingly relied upon the sale of treasury bonds to finance its expenditure. Worse still, businesses and households (perhaps even the federal government) that need to roll over debt (taking out a new loan to paay back an old debt) will be caught in a firestorm. More companies may go bankrupt as they fail to pay back their debts, leading to rising NPLs and threatening bank failure. In the end, the economy may very well shrink.



Inflation may eventually be brought back down to acceptable levels that allow the central bank to lower interest rates, but probably only after years of economic contraction and devastating unemployment. The price will be too high. It may not even be worth it. Poland, for instance, has historically had persistent double-digit inflation, but it also had robust GDP growth. Poland would not be the East European development miracle of today had it sacrificed economic growth in the name of single-digit inflation. It was able to get past its inflationary events without bulldozing its economy because it did not dare to float its currency and use exchange rates as monetary policy instruments until the turn of the century.

When should Ethiopia lift exchange rate controls?

Only when the economy is not prone to such high inflation as we now have at 35pc. There are fundamental challenges that will, and should, push further away exchange rate liberalisation so economic output is not devastated. This includes the ongoing phasing out of subsidies, especially on fuel, that will continue to exert upward pressure on the rise in the cost of goods and services. The other is supply constraints, especially on food, as in the drought conditions in the east and southeastern parts of the country.

Whenever inflation is pushed upwards, the Birr will risk losing its value. The central bank does not worry too much about this because it controls exchange rates. If it gives up this power, and people can freely rush to dump Birr for the dollar, it will be forced to respond in a manner that harms economic growth.

Turkey also faces this dilemma. Annual inflation there is 49pc, the highest in two decades. Everybody talks about the pressure the Lira is under as it loses its value but the only prescription economists are suggesting is increasing interest rates. This is because the only thing Turkey’s central bank can do is tweak interest rates. It has long ago lost exchange rates as monetary policy instruments after the Lira was floated. Lowering economic output is the only alternative remaining.



PUBLISHED ON Feb 12,2022 [ VOL 22 , NO 1137]



Christian Tesfaye (christian.tesfaye@addisfortune.net) is a researcher and Fortune's Deputy Editor-in-Chief whose interests run amok in the directions of political thought, markets, society and pop culture.






Editors' Pick




Editorial




Fortune news


Back
WhatsApp
Telegram
Email